logo

83 pages 2 hours read

Karl Polanyi

The Great Transformation

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 1944

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Part 1Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Part 1: “The International System”

Part 1, Chapter 1 Summary: “The Hundred Year’s Peace”

Polanyi discusses the economic and political origins of the collapse of 19th century civilization, which he believes rested on four institutions: 1) the balance of power system, 2) the international gold standard, 3) the self-regulating market, and 4) the liberal state. The gold standard’s failure—which arose as a result of the self-regulating market—predicated civilization’s collapse, as the other institutions had already been sacrificed in an attempt to salvage it.

This collapse was a series of cycles in which society tried to save itself but ended up endangering itself in other ways. Polanyi admits that his analysis may seem overly simplistic, as civilization exists as a kind of living being, yet this example of civilization is unique in that it was defined by these four institutions. He speaks to the apparent suddenness of the catastrophe that has befallen mankind, which has actually been building for a while: “A reasoned analysis of the catastrophe must account both for the tempestuous action and the quiet dissolution” (4). He believes that his work is not historical but rather seeks to illuminate the present by analyzing the past. Polanyi argues that the world economy failed, leading to the failure of the balance-of-power system to ensure peace; however, it was the idea of the self-regulating market—and the social and technological upheaval that arose as a result—that led to civilization’s breakdown.

From 1815-1914, there was an unheard-of period of relative peace in Western civilization, during which major countries fought little and for short durations, if at all. This peace existed in spite of the causes for conflict, as revolutions spread throughout Europe, empires fell, the East was forcibly opened to the West, Africa was parceled out to European colonizers, and America and Russia gained traction as world powers. Nonetheless, “every single one of these conflicts was localized” (6).

This alleged peace came about through various institutions, both secular and religious, imposing hegemony. Paradoxically, peace existed through the balance of power and the threat of war, although Polanyi believes it was more a result of mutual interest of peaceful business, which arose out of the French and Industrial revolutions. Those who espoused this new peace were those who benefitted from it and did everything in their power to assure its continuation. However, these interests had to be translated into politics and Polanyi lists several examples in which major countries succeeded in averting wars by maintaining the balance of power. Major powers also prevented smaller countries from disturbing the status quo, thereby also ensuring peace. Polanyi gives a number of examples which might negatively affect the peace to be gained from this balance-of-power approach, which does not take into account the variations in human behavior: “It is a commonplace that to ensure peace one must eliminate the causes of war; but it is not generally realized that to do so the flow of life must be controlled at its source” (9).

Polanyi talks about how the Holy Alliance (a coalition of Austria, Russia, and Prussia) sought to do this with a hierarchy of blood and grace, which was succeeded by the Concert of Europe (founded by the three countries above, along with the United Kingdom), which lacked everything that bound the Holy Alliance together yet still managed to maintain peace through haute finance. Haute finance (investment banking and corporate finance) linked the political and economic global spheres, providing the framework for international peace that the Powers could neither maintain nor establish by themselves as the Concert of Europe only acted sporadically. Haute finance was independent of yet worked closely with local governments and central banks:“Both the personnel and the motives of this singular body invested it with a status the roots of which were securely grounded in the private sphere of strictly commercial interest” (10).

This happened via groups like the Rothschilds, who were not beholden to one specific state and often made their money off of local—yet not global—wars. Haute finance was organizationally complex, as it encompassed both government financing and foreign investment; all of the banks in the Powers played a role in maintaining global security, although peace was not the goal but rather a happy byproduct of haute finance, whose only goal was gain.

During this time, nations made little distinction between economic and political power, although “power had precedence over profit” (12) and even created enemies between the Powers, such as the enmity between France and Germany after 1870, which spilled into the countries’ respective economic policies. Similarly, although other scholars have argued that Germany and England’s agreement on the Baghdad Railway demonstrates that WWI had nothing to do with economic expansionism, Polanyi argues that the treaty demonstrates the inevitability of conflict as a result of economics. Politics often played a major role in the continued tension between Powers as they vied for colonial supremacy through economic tactics:“The influence that haute finance exerted on the Powers was consistently favorable to European peace. And this influence was effective to the degree to which the governments themselves depended upon its cooperation in more than one direction” (14).

Finance acted as a moderator between smaller states through the interactions between loans, credit, and good behavior. Once countries adopted the gold standard, England, for example, could use economics to bend them to her will. In this way, colonialism and economics went hand in hand. As the Great Powers extended their influence especially through railways, the greatest threat to their empires became a war amidst themselves. Polanyi uses Turkey’s defaulting on financial agreements as evidence of how unofficial representatives of haute finance maintained peace despite latent tensions. Trade became synonymous with peace, as it “was now dependent upon an international monetary system which could not function in general war” (16).

However, capitalism and colonialism are by default violent, although they also prevent great wars from breaking out by localizing the conflicts so as to not hurt international capital while bolstering national finance. International laws safeguarded business—by allowing commerce between hostile entities, for example—even in times of war, which had never happened before. Polanyi compares this to the previous feudalism of the Holy Alliance:

In every case peace was maintained not simply through the chancelleries of the Great Powers but with the help of concrete organized agencies acting in the service of general interests […] only in the background of the new economy could the balance-of-power system make general conflagration avoidable (18).

While the Holy Alliance enacted peace on a continental scale, the Concert of Europe did it on a global scale. The international financial system was such that it needed peace in order to function, bending otherwise hostile countries to its will. Without this system, the Concert of Europe would have not been sustainable. In Bismarck’s Germany (1861-90), for example, peace was enforced at the cost of others, while ensuring the balance of power; free trade gave way to protectionism and colonial expansion, but Bismarck lost control to Great Britain. Relative security continued despite an increase in tensions, although Great Britain’s 1904 deal with France and subsequent alliance with Russia paved the way for the dissolution of the Concert of Europe and the rise of two hostile groups of power, ultimately breaking the balance of power and resulting in World War I. 

Part 1, Chapter 2 Summary:“Conservative Twenties, Revolutionary Thirties Summary”

Polanyi states that “[t]he breakdown of the international gold standard was the invisible link between the disintegration of the world economy which started at the turn of the century and the transformation of a whole civilization in the thirties” (21). He argues that no one understood the political nature of the global financial system until it had already begun dissolving at a rate that surprised everyone. Part of the reason for its dissolution was the vehemence with which liberal economists—and the democratic countries whose economies they policed—held onto the rigidity of the gold standard, forcing the market economy to essentially collapse in on itself while they stood in denial.

Many people attributed the defeat of the market economy to Word War I; however, World War I did not cause the dysfunction in global political and economic systems: “In reality, the postwar obstacles to peace and stability derived from the same sources from which the Great War itself had sprung” (22), namely political and economic tension. The disarmament of defeated nations as per treaties prevented a balance of power, inhibiting a true League of Nations from forming. However, the public largely believed that the League would keep peace through open dialogue with hostile powers, despite this peace being impossible:“The only alternative to this disastrous condition of affairs was the establishment of an international order endowed with an organized power which would transcend national sovereignty” (23). Of course, no country would willingly submit to what they considered violations of their national sovereignty. Economically, however, the League was much more successful, as statesmen like Woodrow Wilson recognized the interdependence of peace and trade. The League reconstructed international currency and credit organization, relying heavily on haute finance. The postwar decade attempted to return to the systemic structures of the past; however, this eventually failed, resulting in the transformation of the 1930s.

The revolutions in Central and Eastern Europe from 1917-1920—with the exception of Russia—saw a return to more or less the same systems as before WWI, which were based on the ideals of the English, American, and French revolutions. However, these ideals began to dissolve in the 1930s, indicated by the entirely new international context witnessed in England’s abandonment of the gold standard and America’s New Deal, for example. Polanyi argues that the cause of this upheaval lay in the dissolution of the global economy, which was finally broken by World War I and its treaties:“This became apparent in the twenties when there was hardly an internal crisis in Europe that did not reach its climax on an issue of foreign currency” (24). Polanyi lists such issues, demonstrating how the US became linked to these internal issues by trying to stabilize various European currencies.

The first problem arose at a national level, in which various currencies lost all value, creating a rift between these nations and their neighbors that reverberated throughout these societies. Polanyi writes that“[c]urrency had become the pivot of national politics” (25), in which every individual felt the repercussions of currency instability. All countries and people upheld the sovereignty of the gold standard, uniting socialists and liberals. As defeated countries starved themselves to accrue gold, France and Great Britain’s stress on their economies showed as they tried to stabilize these countries’ currencies.

They then looked to the United States for aid, and when the US crashed after years of inflation in 1929, the effects rippled throughout Europe. When the US gave up the gold standard in 1933, the traditional global economy completely dissolved:

Although everybody agreed that stable currencies ultimately depended upon the freeing of trade, all except dogmatic free traders knew that measures had to be taken immediately which would inevitably restrict foreign trade and foreign payments (28).

These efforts to protect the external value of currency effectively strangled trade, forcing people into autarchized economies. When the gold standard finally fell, all the sacrifices nations “made to restore it had now to be made over again so that we might live without it” (28), using the same systems to accomplish this new goal.

The fall of the gold standard restructured these institutions to the point that they were nearly unrecognizable. Liberal states were replaced with dictatorships as the free markets were replaced by new economies. Some nations became obsessed with imposing their ideology on the world, while other nations desired to free people from this oppression. Polanyi talks about the symbiosis of national groups and social institutions in the struggle for survival. Nations believe that they have engendered social change but in reality they are just the beneficiaries of the inevitable, as Germany realized, manipulating the social change in the 1930s:

The distinction between World Wars I and II is apparent: the former was still true to nineteenth-century type—a simple conflict of powers, released by the lapse of the balance-of-power system; the latter already formed part of the world upheaval (30).

The rise of individual powers allowed for the rise of fascism and socialism, although Polanyi argues their WWII roles are not the concern of this book but rather part of the story. He restates his thesis, arguing the mythic nature of the self-regulating market was limited by its singular principle of gain. He talks about the rise of this system during England’s Industrial Revolution, whereby it spread to Europe and America to shape a global economy that would eventually end in catastrophe.

Part 1 Analysis

The first section of Polanyi’s work primarily deals with the issues surrounding peace. However, as Polanyi makes abundantly clear, peace does not seem to actually mean peace during this time period. Throughout the alleged Hundred Years’ Peace, conflict brewed throughout the Powers. Tensions rose between various great powers, although these were usually pursued in localized conflicts. Despite the ubiquity of tensions that Polanyi notes, peace also served as a kind of interest. In this way, the very nature of peace becomes economized; that is, peace becomes expressed as a kind of commodity in and of itself. Polanyi demonstrates that the pursuit of gain was so complete that it rendered peace—something once thought to exclusively relate to social conditions—as a thing which could also be gained. However, there is a kind of reciprocity in this commodity, as the more peace one accumulates or accrues, the more trade benefits, which then in turn leads to more peace. However, Polanyi also points this out as a possible unraveling point for the free-market economy that relied so heavily on peace; namely, that once peace started unraveling—in mounting tensions and the increase in conflict—peace became an interest or a commodity that could easily dissolve.

Polanyi also talks at great length about the global belief in the gold standard. He believes that nations around the world held the gold standard as a kind of divine force, using language in terms of economy that resembles the language of religion. Polanyi refers to the self-regulating market as a kind of trinity that involves the balance of power, the gold standard, and the liberal state. In this way, the free-market economy became a uniting factor that all nations seemed to strive towards.

Polanyi infers that the economy became possibly even more than a global religion; it seemed to become a god of sorts, so that all nations worked towards appeasing this divine being. Their strategy for appeasement wasn’t the typical offering for divinity, but rather a continued persistence in the maintenance and stabilization of this ideology. As such, Polanyi believed that the gold standard became a symbol of world solidarity. However, the awesome power of this unification could only last for so long before reality set in, as the utopia prescribed by the self-regulating market could not actually be achieved. Polanyi presents the dissolution of the gold standard with a kind of apocalyptic certainty, as he believes that the gold standard could never have succeeded and even seems surprised that it was maintained for as long as it was. Polanyi seems less surprised by the ramifications of the Great Depression than he is that the world would choose to revert to this archaic and idealistic market economy that had failed so miserably before. 

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text