77 pages • 2 hours read
G. Edward GriffinA modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
Content Warning: This section discusses antisemitism.
The economic environment following the Civil War was volatile. The late 19th century in America saw four major economic panics. Congress’s response to each was to reduce requirements of specie-backed loans. Legislation in 1874 allowed banks to solely back loans with government bonds. Although the panics were blamed on seasonal agricultural needs, Griffin points out that the panics happen roughly every 11 years, not every season. These panics resulted in hundreds of banks closing in a roughly 50-year period. During this time, the Morgan Firm didn’t just survive these panics but thrived in their wake.
The Morgan Firm was founded in 1837 by George Peabody who established an investment firm based on import/export business from the United States to England. In 1864, Peabody passed the firm on to Junius Morgan who changed the name to J.S. Morgan and Company. The company was based in London, but J.P. Morgan, Junius’s son, established the New York branch after working with American investment companies. Near the turn of the 20th century, J.P. Morgan Jr. went to London to learn British banking, specifically the central bank system in Britain and Europe.
Griffin insinuates that the connection between the Morgan Firm and the Rothschild House was established early on and allowed the Rothschilds to establish a concealed foothold in American trade and finance. The Morgan House remained profitable following the 1857 panic primarily by receiving a significant loan from the Bank of England for their British office, which likely would have been impossible if the Rothschilds had lobbied against it. Griffin claims that the Rothschilds chose the Morgan Firm to avoid the backlash from antisemitic businesses and politicians at the time. He further claims that J.P. Morgan Jr. portrayed himself as an antisemite to put like-minded investors and members of Congress at ease when, in 1896, the government needed a large loan of gold. J.P. Morgan acted as primary lender. Griffin claims that the Rothschilds provided the funding.
At the end of WWI, Britain wanted to return to the gold standard. There were three reasons to return to the gold standard: to increase consumer confidence, to use it as currency between nations, and to reduce the inflationary effect of fiat money. However, England had engaged in various policies related to wages and welfare during the war which artificially set the pound sterling above market value. Prices of English goods were inflated, and England began to spend more on imports than it made on exports. This resulted in a depression, making it necessary to allow the pound’s value to be determined by the international currency market. Instead of allowing market forces to function to eventually stabilize the economy, England used its power in the League of Nations to require other European nations to base their currency on the pound rather than gold. The Bank of England would guarantee the currency and in effect, Griffin argues, become the central bank of Europe.
Although this aided England substantially, the strength of the American dollar on the international market was still a threat. Griffin claims that Montagu Norman and Benjamin Strong conspired with French and German bank leaders to inflate the US dollar to benefit England in the late 1920s. The impetus behind this, Griffin says, was partially pressure from central bankers like J.P. Morgan and the Rothschilds. The other element was a desire on the part of idealistic politicians and financiers to manufacture a “one-world government.”
American banking after the Civil War and prior to the Federal Reserve Act had become more centralized but was still lacking a “lender of last resort” (403). In addition to the national banks created in the wake of the Civil War, many new banks opened in the south and west which refused to join the national system and competed with the national banks. Non-national banks outnumbered and outpaced national banks the year the Federal Reserve Act was passed. In addition to the direct banking competition, 70% of investment capital came from within businesses instead of through bank loans.
As the Morgan Firm and German banking firm Kuhn, Loeb & Company got larger, Griffin claims, they began to cooperate rather than compete. However, with new powers coming into the inner circle of banking, especially John D. Rockefeller, the small group at the top wanted to prevent any more newcomers. Griffin argues that within any cartel there is an inherent threat that one member will want to gain more power and money to rise above the others and potentially break the agreements that protect the whole. Therefore, after Rockefeller rose to financial power rivaling Morgan, they agreed to advance a strategy to protect their insular interests.
Griffin claims that the mechanism of protection was the federal government. In 1908, Congress passed the Aldrich-Vreeland Act, spearheaded by Nelson Aldrich. The Act allowed national banks to create emergency fiat currency and created a National Monetary Commission. The Commission was created to investigate and determine how to stabilize the banking system. It was led by Aldrich who focused all the Commission’s study on European central banking. Aldrich’s networking and study led to the Jekyll Island meeting.
In Griffin’s version of events, there was a five-part goal for those at the meeting: stop small bank competition; make the money supply elastic; pool bank resources to a central reserve; shift losses to taxpayers; and “convince Congress that the scheme was a measure to protect the public” (408). The first four goals would all be contained in a single piece of legislation. To accomplish the last goal, they would have to avoid the appearance of a central bank; instead, the bank would appear to be part of the government. They would use the public’s anger and frustration at recent banking instability as primary fuel. To further avoid public push-back, they would need academics to sanction the project, and the heads of Wall Street (especially Morgan and Rockefeller) would need to speak out publicly against the plan.
Aldrich publicly asserted that the Federal Reserve System would not be a bank. The movement to a true central bank, Griffin claims, would be gradual. Initially the System would appear decentralized and only over time would function similarly to the Bank of England. The Aldrich Bill was touted as a measure to prevent banking monopolies. In essence, the institution proposed in the Bill was like the previous Banks of the United States. The one major difference was that the Federal Reserve would be given the power to create legal tender in paper form.
Professor J. Laurence Laughlin at the University of Chicago was selected to head the National Citizen’s League whose mission was to educate the public and lobby the government for banking reform. Woodrow Wilson was another prominent academic who, Griffin says, had long been indebted to the high financiers. When the Aldrich Bill failed to be brought to a vote and Aldrich was voted out of the Senate, the Democrats came to power both in Congress and in President Woodrow Wilson, a Democrat.
Griffin traces the three-way presidential campaign in 1912 between incumbent William Howard Taft, Woodrow Wilson, and spoiler Teddy Roosevelt. Wilson, Griffin says, was the most attractive candidate to further the Federal Reserve plan. According to Griffin, Taft was only nominally funded to keep up appearances, while Wilson, who espoused supposedly anti-central bank views in keeping with his party, was indebted to Wall Street. Roosevelt, Griffin claims, was funded primarily by the Morgan Group as a third-party candidate. The goal was to elect Wilson, and although he didn’t receive the majority of the popular vote, he beat both Roosevelt and Taft to become President.
There was still a cadre of politicians opposed to central banking led by William Jennings Bryan. Wilson’s adviser, E.M. House, provided the strategy to defeat this opposition. Griffin describes the level of power and influence that House wielded in the Wilson presidency through biographies and excerpts from House’s personal journal. House provided Wilson with much of the information relevant to banking and banking reform and was the mastermind behind most of Wilson’s finance decisions for the nation.
After the failure of the Aldrich Bill, the National Citizens’ League advanced a plan to create a new bill centered around banking reform. The new bill was spearheaded by Virginia Congressman Carter Glass, who had vocally opposed the Aldrich Bill. Griffin claims that the drafting of the bill was deceptive in practice, primarily because, according to Griffin, the new Glass-Owen Bill was identical in substance to the Aldrich Bill. To lend credibility to the bill, Glass held public hearings to include bipartisan input on the Bill’s content. However, Griffin says that the Bill had already been written and was not changed in response to those hearings. Aldrich and Vanderlip publicly condemned the new Bill, which Griffin says they did to convince the smaller banks and the public that Morgan and the Rockefellers were fearful of the legislation. Glass directly told smaller banks that if they didn’t support his Bill, they were likely to fall prey to more controlling legislation.
The primary roadblocks to the Bill were Bryan’s objections that private banks would be issuing private money. Therefore, the Bill’s sponsors had to agree that the notes issued by the Fed would be Treasury currency and that the governing body of the Fed would be appointed by the federal government. These concessions were made, and Bryan became a supporter of the Bill, which passed as the Federal Reserve Act in 1913.
Griffin discusses the functions of the Federal Reserve and its role in the Great Depression of the 1930s. He asserts that the original Act was deliberately vague in order to invite new interpretations and revisions, and that there have been 195 amendments to the Act since its passage.
Benjamin Strong was the first Governor of the New York Federal Reserve Branch and acted as the leader of the system. He was closely connected to the major financiers in New York and England. Griffin claims that the inflation in the US which benefitted England was a function of the Federal Reserve under the influence of Benjamin Strong. He asserts that men like Strong who have served as Fed leaders have questionable loyalties.
Following WWI, farmers in America had become highly prosperous. They placed most of their money into local banks which had not joined the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Farm Loan Board offered these prosperous farmers large amounts of credit at low interest rates. The Fed then raised interest rates steeply, which prevented the farmers from either paying the interest or borrowing what they needed for maintenance. The farmers and the banks went out of business, and the entire nation was negatively affected by the Fed’s lowering and raising interest rates rapidly.
According to Griffin, there are two primary ways in which the Fed manipulates the economy. The first way is by setting the required reserve ratio, or telling banks what percent of their deposits they must keep in reserve. If the Fed lowers that ratio, then banks can loan more, without the loans getting repaid or getting new deposits which puts more currency into the economy. The other method is by influencing the commercial loan interest rate. It accomplishes this through the discount window. Once the bank has loaned out all it is allowed to loan, it either must collect loans, gain new deposits, put its profits in reserve, or borrow from an outside source. Most of the time, banks borrow from the Fed by “going to the discount window” (438). When the banks acquire that money, they loan it at the same reserve ratio. The more available loans, the lower the interest rate, so the Fed can lower or raise the interest rate on loans in the marketplace by adjusting the interest rate at the discount window.
Both these methods have limits. Eventually, the banks won’t need or want more loans because their customers won’t want more loans, and the lowest reserve ratio is zero. In that case, the Fed can buy and sell securities or government bonds in the bond market. That method also has a limit based on how many bonds are available for sale. The final method by which the Fed puts money into the economy is the “acceptance window.”
When a large international sale occurs, it is common practice for the buyer and seller to use Bankers’ Acceptances to facilitate the sale. The buyer’s bank promises the seller’s bank to cover the cost of the sale when the buyer receives the goods. The seller’s bank pays the seller the agreed-upon price. Both banks collect a small fee for this service, but the return comes out of the completed sale, and it can take time for the seller’s bank to collect the profit. The seller’s bank can offer the acceptance to the marketplace for a percentage of what their fee would have been. The percentage at which the acceptance is sold is called the “rate of discount.” These markets were unpopular in the US until the Fed set the discount rate of acceptances low enough to entice sellers to offer more for sale. That only takes care of the supply side of the equation, so the Fed promised to buy all the acceptances. According to Griffin, that action encouraged banks to buy more acceptances knowing that the Fed would cover them at any time. The creation of this market hugely benefitted a few financiers, but ultimately the fiat money flowing into the economy created an expansion of the money supply so large that, Griffin claims, it led to the Great Depression.
During WWI Congress funded the war effort primarily through the sale of Liberty and Treasury bonds. Some of these were purchased by the public with savings or loans, which only slightly inflate the economy. The majority were bought by the Fed. The bonds then became the basis of money in the US economy. The Fed bought the bonds in part to lower interest rates in the States to encourage borrowing from abroad which resulted in American money moving overseas.
Whether by accident or design, the government discovered that the Federal Reserve System could provide funding without formal taxation by using the open market. Benjamin Strong, Griffin argues, used the open market to transfer wealth from the United States to England. He created the Open-Market Committee that resulted in the New York Federal Reserve Bank, of which he was governor, to carry out all open-market operations on behalf of the Fed.
Because of artificially low interest rates, more credit was available to foreign nations, major companies, and average consumers in the 1920s. Although the currency in circulation remained relatively static, there was still significant inflation in the guise of “money substitutes, such as bonds and loan contracts” (446). Before the Fed, Griffin asserts, bank failures occurred, and affected some consumers, but largely these were isolated events, and the economy in those areas recovered quickly. After the Fed, however, the booms and busts were extended and seemed to build upon one another. Because the banking system was now connected and the banks weren’t allowed to fail, the challenges of one bank spread to the entire US economy.
Griffin follows what he calls a roller coaster of booms and busts throughout the 1920s, culminating in the Great Depression. He argues that the sixth reason to abolish the Fed is that instead of stabilizing the economy as it purports to do, it destabilizes it through the very measures it claims create stability.
Using the example of the tulip market in Holland in the 1600s, Griffin describes a tendency in people to behave like a herd. Griffin points to lotteries and casinos as evidence that people will often risk more than is prudent for the possibility of a big payoff. That tendency drove individuals and banks to speculate on the stock market during the cheap and easily available credit crafted by the Fed in the 1920s.
The difference between the stock market boom and the other booms and busts of the decade was that the Fed did not step in to smooth the coming bust as it had in the past. At least, Griffin argues, not for the public. In February of 1929, following a meeting between Secretary of the Treasury Mellon and Norman Montagu, the Fed warned its members to liquidate their stocks.
Even after the major players liquidated their stock holdings, the public was actively reassured by the financiers and government that the economy was strong. Griffin claims that following clandestine visits from Montagu and secret meetings between Treasury and Federal Reserve representatives, the Fed and the Bank of England began to shrink reserves in August of 1929 and raise interest rates in both nations. In late October, the market crashed and speculators sold everything. The buyers were largely those who had been warned and had shored up their wealth in cash and gold, so had the money to buy the steeply discounted stocks.
Griffin offers another law of human nature and economics: that any man given the temptation and opportunity is likely to privilege himself at the expense of others. The power to control the money supply of a nation will result in a few getting richer at the expense of everyone else.
The stock market crash didn’t result in the Great Depression on its own. Certainly, some people invested their life savings on risky loans and lost that, but those who had invested with real money largely kept their stocks and recovered as the market recovered. What Griffin says ought to have happened was a short panic and a quick recovery, but instead the government intervened. Legislation marketed as rescue plans to shore up from the Crash, in addition to more money pumped into the economy by the Fed, increased the economic devastation rather than counteracting it. At the end of the decade, even with all the reforms, it still took another World War to recover from the Depression.
Throughout the book, Griffin’s text exhibits what extremism scholar Michael Barkun has identified as the three central characteristics of a conspiracy theory: nothing happens by accident, nothing is as it seems, and everything is connected (Barkun, Michael. A Culture of Conspiracy: Apocalyptic Visions in Contemporary America. University of California Press, 2003). One of Griffin’s primary rhetorical strategies is personification: He characterizes the central banking system embodied by the Federal Reserve as a living being, The Creature from Jekyll Island. He elaborates on the metaphor in his introduction to Part 5: “The Creature moved into its final lair in 1913 and has snorted and thrashed about the landscape ever since” (384). Describing an institution as a living being allows Griffin to treat the Fed as an entity independent of the various people who have contributed to its creation, development, and operations over more than a century. By painting the Fed as a creature, Griffin can ascribe a single, frightening motive to every action the Federal Reserve banks have taken. Through the Creature and its intentions and actions, every aspect of the economic history of the US is connected. At the end of the book, he further personifies collectivism as a species of which the Creature is a member. Implying that the Fed is a living creature whose motives and actions are dictated by its genetic connection to its species, collectivism, allows Griffin to ascribe fundamentally malicious, centralized motives to what are actually institutions staffed by thousands of individual people, whose decisions, like any person’s, may not always prove to be ideal in the long run. In fact, contemporary members of the Federal Reserve have recognized the institution’s past mistakes, even issuing a public apology for the Fed’s role in the Crash of 1929 and the Great Depression (Bernanke, Ben. “Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke At the Conference to Honor Milton Friedman.” The Federal Reserve Board, 8 Nov 2002).
Chapters 20 and 21 attempt to show that the Fed, along with every other aspect of global finance and government, are connected to the “cartel” of the Rothschilds, the Morgans, and the Rockefellers, and their supposed goal of forming a “one-world government.” Griffin’s allegation draws from the New World Order conspiracy theory, which alleges that since the early 20th century a cabal of “globalists” have sought total control of the world through secret means, often related to international banking connections, and often with the final goal of establishing communist rule (Flores, Myles. “The New World Order: The Historical Origins of a Dangerous Modern Conspiracy Theory.” Center on Terrorism, Extremism, and Counterterrorism Publications, Middlebury Institute of International Studies at Monterey, 30 May 2022). Griffin ties these financial powers together partially to further his argument about human nature, but also to strengthen his assertion that the Fed was born out of a fear of competition among financiers. To support that contention, he needs all these different people to share a single goal even when their actions and opinions seem at odds—and even when there is no documentary evidence for their collusion. Griffin even questions the veracity of his primary source for the account of George Peabody and Nathan Rothschild’s conspiratorial cooperation: “Mullins does not give a reference for the source of this story, and one cannot help being skeptical that such details could be proved. Nevertheless, a secret arrangement of this kind is not as absurd as it may sound” (390). Griffin admits that Edward Mullins’s claim lacks any support and that the claim is a stretch. Instead of facts, he insinuates that if a “secret meeting” could theoretically be possible, it must be probable, and therefore true. Accepting Mullins’s claims despite the lack of evidence enables Griffin to make similarly baseless claims elsewhere.
Another one of Griffin’s main argumentative practices in this section is alleging secret motives for historical figures in order to explain away actions and statements that run contrary to his thesis. This move is particularly prominent in his account of the creation and passage of the Federal Reserve Act. As he has in previous sections, Griffin mixes facts and misinformation in his retelling. Aldrich and House were indeed central figures in the creation and passage of the Federal Reserve Act. Aldrich remained active in the negotiations leading to the creation of the final bill even after his own was defeated, although contrary to Griffin’s claims, the Glass-Owen bill that passed in 1913 was a compromise bill that differed significantly from the Aldrich Plan. House was one of the key figures in the negotiations that led to the bill’s passage, and Griffin is correct when he says that the House personally helped bring the parties to a compromise. Members of Congress, federal employees, and prominent figures from Wall Street were all involved in the process of forging and passing the bill, which demonstrates The Effect of Finance on Politics which is the primary thrust of the fifth section. Historians and economists alike have criticized the bill that passed, pointing out its flaws and failures, including failures that served various interested parties. However, Griffin’s thesis is that the bill represents a deliberate manipulation by numerous people, many of whom publicly disapproved of or expressed disappointment with the final outcome. To explain away the lack of lock-step agreement among people whom Griffin claims were acting on a single set of conspiratorial goals, he suggests that those people were lying about their beliefs or concerns, either to sway public opinion or maintain a particular public image. For Griffin’s Creature to exist, he must dismiss the evidence that shows that the Fed was a hard-won, imperfect compromise arrived at after extensive negotiations among people with very different goals and values.