57 pages • 1 hour read
Michael E. PorterA modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
In the Preface and Introduction, Porter outlines the broad questions that inform The Competitive Advantage of Nations: “why [...] some social groups, economic institutions, and nations advance and prosper” (xi) and why some firms and industries succeed in certain national contexts, bringing prosperity in their wake, but fail in others. To address these questions, Porter departs from traditional approaches to the question, which have focused on macro-economic issues related to national economies and government. In contrast, Porter begins with the micro-economic foundation of the individual company. By first examining why firms gain competitive advantage, he hopes to address why nations succeed. He looks at successful firms in 10 leading economies: Denmark, Germany, Italy, Japan, Korea, Singapore, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK, and the US. Porter draws case studies from advanced industries in which those nations hold a particular edge.
In Chapter 1 Porter examines various definitions of national competitiveness. As he highlights, this is often considered a function of trade balance. In this view, a competitive nation is one “with a large and positive balance of trade” (5) between exports and imports. However, as he points out, many poorer nations have balanced trade. Meanwhile, wealthier nations often run deficits, most notably the US, which has been in deficit most years since 1970. This discrepancy is partly because trade surpluses can result from low wages and weak currencies. Neither are desirable economic goals—nor are they true indicators of a nation’s industrial strength.
Instead, Porter argues for defining competitiveness by levels of productivity—specifically, by measuring “international success in relatively sophisticated industries and segments of industries involving complex technology and highly skilled human resources” (10). These areas, which offer the greatest potential for high and sustainable wage and productivity growth, include aerospace, software design, and pharmaceutical industries—contrasted with basic manufacturing or industries involving the extraction of raw materials.
Next, Porter examines why firms in certain nations develop and sustain advantage in the former areas. To tackle this question in more depth, he explores the classical theories of international competition. Adam Smith, in The Wealth of Nations (1776), argues that nations would trade in the goods and services where they were the lowest-cost producer. Others later refined this notion, first David Ricardo and then, in the 1930s, Heckscher and Ohlin. The latter created a theory of trade “based on the idea that all nations have equivalent technology but differ in their endowment of so-called factors of production such as land, labour, natural resources, and capital” (11). As such, on this theory, nations would trade in the industries in which abundance of a particular factor gave them a relative advantage. For example, nations with a surplus of low-cost labor, like India, would export labor intensive goods. In contrast, nations with an abundance of a particular natural resource are likely to develop industries, and to export, in those areas. Sweden, for instance, gained advantage in the steel industry because it had an abundance of high-quality iron ore.
However, while this theory may have been appliable to industry in the 19th century, Porter suggests that it is insufficient to explain competitive advantage in the late 20th century for several reasons. First, the rate of technological change is far greater in the 20th century. This means that nations and firms are more likely to have different technological levels and that basic factor advantages are easier to overcome. For instance, better technology can improve automation and thereby negate the advantage of abundant cheap labor. Second, most advanced nations enjoy comparable factor endowments. Most developed nations have educated, skilled workforces and good transport and communication infrastructure. Thus, broad factor endowments play a minimal role in competitive edge between them. Finally, the increasingly global character of companies nullifies factor advantages of access to cheap labor, raw materials, or capital because firms can source these factors, if necessary, from other nations or locate aspects of production outside their home base to take advantage of low costs.
As such, a new theory of international competition is necessary. This must be one that gets beyond merely looking at static factor costs on undifferentiated products. Rather, it must involve a more complex model of competitive advantage incorporating the realities of differential and rapidly evolving products and technologies. Porter state his intent to outline such a theory in the rest of the text.
The definition of national competitiveness and what determines it may feel like a technical, academic question. Alternatively, it may seem an immutable issue of natural resources and culture. However, what Porter refers to as “traditional thinking” has had great real-world impact. The standard view, which sees competitiveness mainly in terms of “cost efficiency due to factor or scale advantages” (20), has influenced government policy and hence millions of lives. It has done so via the implementation of what can be broadly called laissez-faire policies, which look to gain competitive advantage for their nation’s firms by seeking ways to lower costs—for example, by relaxing environmental or safety regulations. Laws against labor unionization have supressed wage rises, while corporate tax cuts have benefited employers. Meanwhile, developing countries have been encouraged to utilize their “factor advantage” of cheap labor by specializing in low-technology, labor-intensive industries.
However, these policies have often failed. If the goal of competitive advantage is to improve the lives of a nation’s populace and not an end in itself, then reduced environmental and labor protection appears counterproductive. One ostensible aim of national competitiveness is to provide plentiful employment opportunities, but if all the jobs created are poorly paid, insecure, or dangerous, one might wonder whether it is worth the cost. Worse, any advantage gained in this way is “often exceedingly fleeting” (15). As Porter points out, “competitive advantage that rests on factor costs is vulnerable to even lower factor costs somewhere else” (15). For example, in industries that rely on low labor costs through lax safety standards, a nation willing to sacrifice such standards further than other nations are can easily surpass them. Indeed, the very nature of such advantages is that they are short-term and easily imitable. The same is true for nations that depend on low corporate tax rates to sustain firm profits or attract investment. Rival nations can quickly undercut them.
As such, laissez-faire policies have rarely achieved sustained competitiveness. They have instead often led to a short-term, zero-sum “race to the bottom” between nations. Consequently, they have encouraged a hostility toward the notion of competition itself. Because laissez-faire or “neo-liberal” competition policy can lead to lowered wages or conditions or to the loss of industries in nations altogether, one response has been to advocate insulation from competition. This has often taken the form of protectionism. Tariffs are imposed on imports, thereby artificially increasing the price of foreign goods and making home-produced ones seem relatively cheaper. Another response has been industrial policy. As pursued at various times in France, South Korea, and Japan, industrial policy involves “core practices of targeting, subsidies, and cooperative activity” (xxvi). This means giving financial and logistical help to certain firms or industries deemed important, such as car manufacture, and trying to guarantee their success.
Unfortunately, such interventionist policies are rarely much more successful than laissez-faire ones. In fact, they are almost as equally short term. By giving home firms artificial advantages in cost terms, via subsidies and import tariffs, they only store up problems for the future. Firms receive little incentive to innovate or operate more efficiently. Thus, superior foreign competition, the reason for protection in the first place, pulls further ahead. Eventually, support for the industry becomes too costly and, once withdrawn, leaves the home firm unable to survive on a level playing field against foreign rivals. Alternatively, many nations adopt protectionist policies. Everyone protects their industries, and everyone is worse off due to lower-quality products and higher prices.
However, as Porter argues, these are not the only alternatives. One is only obligated to accept this dichotomy between laissez-faire and intervention if one also accepts that competition is fundamentally about factors of production and costs. If, instead, one adopts a more sophisticated idea of competitiveness, based on advantage through differentiated products and innovation in the most advanced industries, the picture changes: There is no longer a trade-off between competition and social standards. On the contrary, success in high-productivity industries allows for higher wages, more leisure time, and tax revenues to fund public goods. It also allows, as Porter notes, “a nation’s firms to meet stringent social standards which improve the standard of living, such as in health and safety, equal opportunity, and environmental impact” (6). The real question is how government can encourage the conditions in a nation whereby advanced, high-productivity industries flourish. Porter intimates an answer when he writes that “government’s proper role is to push and challenge its industry to advance” (30).
In addition, Porter suggests providing incentives for “upgrading and innovation” (xxvii) rather than stasis. Nevertheless, a full answer relies on identifying, understanding, and assessing the other determinants of competitive advantage besides factor endowments.
Books About Leadership
View Collection
Business & Economics
View Collection
Challenging Authority
View Collection
Class
View Collection
Class
View Collection
Colonialism & Postcolonialism
View Collection
Community
View Collection
Education
View Collection
Equality
View Collection
Globalization
View Collection
Nation & Nationalism
View Collection
Order & Chaos
View Collection
Politics & Government
View Collection
Power
View Collection
Teams & Gangs
View Collection
The Future
View Collection
The Past
View Collection
War
View Collection