logo

57 pages 1 hour read

Michael E. Porter

The Competitive Advantage Of Nations

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 1990

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Part 3, Chapters 9-10Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Part 3: “Nations”

Part 3, Chapter 9 Summary: “Shifting National Advantage”

Having looked at nations that have gained competitive advantage since the 1970s, Porter now examines two nations that have lost, or are in the process of losing, it. The purpose is to gain a deeper understanding of the factors that determine national advantage. The first of these countries is the UK. Despite being the world’s first industrialized nation and its leading industrial power up until the start of the 20th century, Britain has been on “a long slide” (482) since then. Among the advanced nations, it endured the lowest growth in productivity and per capita income in the post-war period. It also lost competitive positions in a large and increasing number of industries. While maintaining positions in consumer packaged goods, confectionary products, household products such as toothpaste and soaps, and financial services, it has lost ground in sophisticated manufacturing. This decline is especially marked in transportation and machinery.

Porter explores the reasons for this. The UK enjoys extensive reserves of capital, a favorable location, and the advantage that English is “the world business language” (496) due to British and then US economic world dominance. However, UK factor creation is poor. As Porter writes, “The British educational system has badly lagged behind that of virtually all the nations we studied” (497). University education tends to be highly theoretical, stressing the humanities or pure science at the expense of practical disciplines like engineering. Meanwhile, the standard of secondary education is inadequate, with post-16 technical colleges both limited and of low status. Additionally, government investment in research and development is insufficient and is skewed toward defense-related areas that are of limited use to industry. Compounding these problems, the UK has low quality and unsophisticated demand due to falling living standards and a traditional reliance on developing nations for export markets. Fractious labor-management relations and a culture of short-term investment decisions, driven by an excessive focus on quarterly share prices, complete the reasons for UK industry failure.

The second declining nation Porter examines is the US. In the 1970s, the American trade position weakened, going into trade deficit for the first time in the 20th century in 1971. In addition, real wages began declining in 1973. These were symptoms of a deeper industrial malaise. While the US maintained positions in computers, packaged software, and consumer packaged goods and services, “there has been a significant loss of competitive advantage in a wide range of US manufacturing industries” (508). These include cars, trucks, machine tools, semiconductors, and consumer electronics. One of the core reasons is that, like with Britain, the US has a poor education system. The best US universities are still world leading, but the standard of education for the average American worker is below that of rival nations, especially in math and science. Porter notes that “school years are short, absenteeism is high, hours spent on homework are low, and competition among students has been de-emphasized” (521). This means that American workers and managers lack the foundation necessary for further training to improve productivity.

American demand conditions have also deteriorated. US consumers are no longer the most affluent. In addition, their penchant for low-cost, mass-produced items means that in many areas, US demand trails the latest world trends, which are toward products that are more specialized, higher quality, and on smaller production runs. US demand has also fallen behind the world trend toward more environmentally conscious products. Compounding these problems, as in the UK, is a business culture that stresses short-term profit over long-term investment. Therefore, owners, managers, and workers often have limited commitment to their firm, and firms excessively pursue mergers to boost share prices—typically at the expense of domestic rivalry.

Part 3, Chapter 10 Summary: “The Competitive Development of National Economies”

Porter generalizes from the countries he examined to outline the broad stages of possible economic development for a nation. All countries do not necessarily pass through each stage, and nations have occasionally leap-frogged past certain stages. However, it is typically necessary to pass through an earlier stage to get to a later one. All national economies fall broadly into one of these categories. The first is the “factor-driven” stage. Most developing countries are at this point, as are nations like Russia and Canada, and it involves competition on basic factors, such as natural resources or low labor costs. The second stage is “investment-driven.” A nation at this stage invests heavily in factors of production like education and infrastructure and purchases licences for foreign technology, which it improves upon. It can thus compete in some advanced manufacturing, although it does so mainly on price. Korea is at the investment-driven stage. The penultimate stage is “innovation-driven,” in which a nation does just not improve on technology from other nations but creates new technology and methods. At this stage, a nation enjoys competitive advantage in the most advanced sectors of industry and usually competes through differentiation and quality. The last stage is “wealth-driven.” This occurs when a rich country loses its competitive edge and is increasingly forced to rely on accumulated wealth from the past. It also occurs in industries related to such wealth, like financial services.

Part 3, Chapters 9-10 Analysis

Porter states that “in the innovation stage, the full ‘diamond’ is in place” (552). When a nation is at the highest stage of competitive advantage, in which it continually innovates in a broad range of advanced industries, all the determinants of national advantage are present—and they are mutually re-enforcing. Leading firms in end-product industries help encourage world-class supplier industries like machinery to serve them. Conversely, world-class supplier companies elevate the quality of end-product firms. Success in world markets causes national income to rise and has a knock-on effect on home demand. As Porter notes, “Consumer demand becomes increasingly sophisticated because of rising personal income, higher levels of education,” and an “increasing desire for convenience” (553). Firms can therefore gain a further edge because increasingly discerning consumers demand the latest and highest-quality products and services. Finally, government has the resources from higher tax revenues—and the will—to invest in advanced factor creation in conjunction with industry, which recognizes the importance of long-term investment and works cooperatively with government toward the common goal of higher productivity.

However, the same processes can work in reverse. When a nation starts to lose competitive advantage and transitions to becoming a “wealth-driven economy” (556), the virtuous cycle described becomes a viscous one. This process starts, as Porter argues, when “the motivation of investors, managers, and individuals shift in ways that undermine sustained investment and innovation” (556). This may result from satiation. After generations of high income and material success, a culture of complacency sets in. The incentives to strive for higher standards in industry, and the sense of why this matters, though keenly felt in the past, weaken. It could also be linked to the diminishing marginal utility of income and a focus on other, non-material values in new generations. A symptom may be, as in Britain and the US, a sense that working in industry is no longer prestigious. Further evidence is a reduced interest in practical, industry-oriented aspects and areas of education.

Whatever the spark, once this malaise begins, it is hard to arrest. The very wealth and early industry success that helped breed a culture of complacency serves at first to mask that a problem exists. Disguising the loss of competitive advantage in advanced industries is the fact that in the short-term, profits in those firms may fall only slowly because of “the momentum created by customer loyalties and established market positions” (557). Customers take time switching to better-quality, more efficiently produced foreign goods. Indeed, profits may rise. This may result from mergers or chronic under-investment, which allows for higher short-term dividend pay-outs. Finally, wealth driven nations can still maintain positions in non-cutting-edge industries and those related to luxury, leisure, or wealth management, as the continued success of financial service and entertainment industries in the UK and US illustrates. In fact, some may even sell or justify this as a positive development, holding that the decline of industry and the relative rise of services is part of an inevitable and beneficial transition to a “post-industrial” or “service-based” society. Such arguments further hinder remedial action to address the problem.

Meanwhile, the underlying cycle of decline continues. As Porter highlights, “industries that are no longer innovating become poor buyers for the industries that supply them” (557). Supplying and related firms decline because they no longer are faced with cutting-edge demand. This in turn weakens, due to poorer inputs, the initial buyer industries. Such problems can then spill over into politics. Competitively weakening, but still large and powerful, firms try “to insulate themselves by influencing government policy” (556). Prompted by fears of mass lay-offs, government may respond by offering subsidies or imposing import tariffs. This temporary salve makes home firms even less competitive.

Almost as bad, it wastes precious and diminishing national resources. With lower tax revenues due to falling national income, and increased spending on welfare due to growing unemployment, industry subsidies draw scarce funds away from essential investment in factor creation. Education and infrastructure quality, the root of many of the nation’s problems, deteriorate further. The nation’s firms fall further behind. In addition, strife between workers and management increases. With pressure on wages and profits, both sides fight over a shrinking national income and struggle to maintain previous positions. In the end, nobody wins. Aside from small groups that control past accumulated wealth, society becomes increasingly poor, divided, and beset by social problems. Whether, and how, a nation can address such a malaise is the topic of the next three chapters.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text