logo

46 pages 1 hour read

Dan Ariely

Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape our Decisions

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2008

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Chapters 7-9Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Chapter 7 Summary: “The Problem of Procrastination and Self-Control: Why We Can’t Make Ourselves Do What We Want to Do”

“Procrastination,” as it is presented in Chapter 7, is when someone delays an action or give up long-term goals in exchange for immediate gratification. Ariely and a colleague set-up an experiment to study “why we lose the fight against procrastination so frequently” (141). The experiment subjects were split into three groups—three college class periods. In the first class, Ariely asked students to pick the dates they would submit each of their papers. Students in this class scheduled their papers across the semester, indicating they were trying to prevent themselves from procrastinating. In the second class, all papers were due by the end of the semester; students could turn in papers throughout the semester, but it was not a requirement. In the third class, Ariely dictated the paper deadlines. The experiment found that students in the third class received the best grades, followed by those in the first and second classes. To Ariely, the findings suggest that tightly restricting freedom might be the best way to overcome procrastination. Even when students recognize they procrastinate, they often do not fully understand their problem or how to set personal deadlines that optimize their performance.

Ariely recognizes that we cannot restrict individual freedom in most real-world situations. He believes “the best course might be to give people an opportunity to commit up front to their preferred path of action” (147), which he calls a commitment mechanism. While this approach (akin to the first class in his experiment) is less effective than restricting freedom (third class), it still encourages people to deal with procrastination.

Chapter 8 Summary: “The High Price of Ownership: Why We Overvalue What We Have”

The opening pages of Chapter 8 reveal a “real-life experiment” (169) that occurred on Duke University’s campus in the spring of 1994. Ariely explains how students camped out in front of the football stadium to go through an intricate selection process for football tickets. The selection process involved a lottery, meaning that not all students who camped out would get tickets. Ariely and a colleague predicted that the students who now had ownership of the tickets would value the tickets more than students who didn’t obtain them, even though they all worked equally hard trying to get them. The researchers thought that perhaps the “endowment effect” was happening, which is when someone values the thing they own more than others value it.

To test this hypothesis, Ariely and his colleague became ticket scalpers. They set out to purchase tickets from some of the students who won them and sell them to students who didn’t. They found that students who were not lucky enough to get a ticket were willing to buy one for less than $200. When Ariely and his colleague asked the non-ticket-holders how they arrived at this price, they noted other ways they could spend the money, such as for foods and drinks at a bar to watch the game. In contrast, students who won tickets were only willing to sell the tickets for several thousand dollars. The ticket holders justified their price to Ariely and his colleague in terms of the memories the experience would create. The researchers also found that not a single ticket holder was willing to sell their ticket for a price that a non-holder was willing to pay.

From a traditional economic perspective, both the ticket holders and non-holders should have valued the ticket equally. However, Ariely’s findings contradict this notion. Despite both groups of students putting the same effort into attempting to get a ticket, the ticket holder imagined “the glory of the game” (172), whereas the non-holder “imagined what else they could buy with the price of the ticket” (172).

Ariely believes “three irrational quirks in our human nature” (173) explain why ownership can cause strange behavior. The first quirk is that people come to love what they own; they associate memories with these items which increases their attachment to them. The second quirk is that rather than focusing on what they might gain from giving up the item, people focus on what they would lose. The final quirk is that people assume others will value the item as much as they themselves do.

Chapter 9 Summary: “Keeping Doors Open: Why Options Distract Us from Our Main Objective”

Chapter 9 opens with the story of Chinese commander Xiang Yu. In 210 BC, Xiang Yu burned his own ships and crushed his army’s cooking pots because without these two items, his army “had no other choice but to fight their way to victory or perish” (183). His army successfully defeated their enemy. This story is remarkable because Xiang Yu’s actions go against normal human behavior. People tend “to keep all our options open” (184) without realizing that they sacrifice something for having all those opportunities.

To better understand the human compulsion to keep doors open, Ariely and a colleague designed a series of experiments called “the ‘door game’” (187). The game was on a computer. In the first experiment, participants had the opportunity to enter one of three rooms simply by clicking on the door that corresponded to the room. Once they were in the room, participants earned money by clicking their mouse. The trick was to find the room with the biggest payout and click as often as possible in the allotted time. This was not a trivial task. Each participant had 100 clicks, and switching rooms used up one click. Ariely notes, “On one hand, switching from one room to another might be a good strategy for finding the biggest payout. On the other hand, running madly from door to door (and room to room) meant that you were burning up your clicks which could otherwise have made you money” (188). This first experiment confirmed what Ariely already suspected about human behavior: People easily pursue a source of satisfaction if there is a clear goal.

Ariely and his colleague then changed the experiment to make a door close after it remained unvisited for 12 clicks. All the participants made less money than in the first experiment because they moved back and forth between doors to make sure none closed. They would have made more money if they had picked a room and stayed there for the duration of the study. Ariely further modified the experiment, telling participants the exact monetary outcomes they could expect from each room, but the results always matched those from the second experiment. The participants maintained “the same irrational excitement about keeping their options open” (191).

To overcome this irrational compulsion to maximize open doors, Ariely suggests that people work to consciously start closing some of them. Because small doors are easier to close than larger ones, Ariely believes people should start there. They need to close doors because indecisiveness has consequences.

Chapters 7-9 Analysis

Chapters 7 through 9 focus on the costs of predictably irrational behaviors. Beginning with problems related to procrastination and self-control, Ariely shows how the need for immediate gratification “wrecks our best-laid plans for dieting, saving money, cleaning the house—the list is endless” (156). One common example is “obsessively checking our e-mails” (157) throughout the day. A recent report found that workers spend more than two work days a week doing this task. E-mail is important because it allows a person to stay in contact with friends and colleagues, but is it worth two full weekdays? Ariely does not believe so. The constant distraction of e-mail means giving up time and energy that could go toward other opportunities.

Ariely moves from procrastination to ownership in Chapter 8. Ownership involves peculiarities, including feeling like something is ours before we actually own it. This feeling means people often make irrational decisions about a purchase. Take an online auction as an example. A bidder starts to imagine that they already own the item they are bidding on. Therefore, people make higher bids as the auction nears its end, often bidding more than originally planned. In the desire to not lose the item that they already feel is theirs, bidders are giving up not only more of their time to put in bids but also more money. They could do other things with that money, like buy a book, go out to dinner, or increase savings.

Chapter 9 focuses on how “our irrational compulsion to keep doors open” (194) results in lost opportunities. For example, someone might spend months deciding between two camera purchases before they make a selection. In doing so, they lose out on the photos they could have taken of their family and friends.

Ariely underscores that it is not easy to stop procrastinating, owning things, or compulsively keeping doors open. He tells readers that despite his “foreknowledge of the difficulty in this decision-making process, I was just as predictably irrational as everyone else” (197). Ariely spent several weeks considering two really similar items: staying at his job at MIT or moving to Stanford. He spent time researching the schools, talking with people at both institutions, and determining which of the two schools better fit his family’s life. He became so obsessed with these two options that he neglected his own research. Like so many, Ariely failed to consider what he was giving up by not making a decision. Ariely’s personal story shows that it is difficult to go against natural human wiring. However, failing to do so means continuing to lose opportunities.

Humans’ strong aversion to loss also causes poor decisions. For example, people have a hard time ratcheting themselves back when they indulge, even if they tell themselves that they will restrain themselves later. Homeownership is a good example. As individuals go through their lives, they often buy bigger and bigger homes. It is difficult to move from a bigger home to a smaller home, even if someone struggles paying the mortgage. Thinking about this loss (i.e., moving to a smaller home) is “psychologically painful” (178). As a result, a person stays in the bigger home, even though the better decision would be to sell it and move to a more affordable, smaller home.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text